I’m really glad to see that this European screw-up is, eventually,
making headlines and that the European Commission is reconsidering the
operational details of its production function method to estimate potential
output and structural deficits (see WSJ).
As reported by the WSJ’s Real Time Brussels blog, the
issue has become important, as the new European Fiscal Compact, which
entered into force on 1 January 2013, requires that the structural deficit for
euro-area Member States be less than 0.5%. So since “the European Commission uses [the structural balance] metric — the actual
government budget balance adjusted for the strength of the economy – to
determine how much austerity is needed; getting it wrong has big consequences.”
The question is whether “getting the structural balance wrong” in
2010 – the time at which Europe started to become obsessed with fiscal
austerity – mattered in driving the amount of consolidation.
I first came across and pointed out the weakness of the structural
balance calculations of the European Commission in 2010 in a series of Goldman
Sachs publications that I then summarized with my co-author Natacha Valla on VoxEU. The basic storyline was and
remains simple. The European Commission drastically revised downward its
estimates of potential GDP as the crisis hit, which automatically increased its
structural deficit measures for European countries.
This raised 2 questions?
1/ Did it make sense? 2/ And did the downward revisions to
potential GDP matter for the size of consolidation packages?
First, did the downward revisions to potential GDP – that the
European Commission introduced early in the crisis – make sense?
The European Commission uses a production function methodology for
calculating potential growth rates and output gaps (see here). It features a simple Cobb
Douglas specification where potential output depends on TFP and a combination
of factor inputs (potential labor and capital). Importantly for what follows,
potential labor input is calculated as:
Working
age Population x Participation rate x Average hours worked x (1 - NAWRU)
It’s important to focus on potential labor input since the bulk of
the revisions applied between 2008 and 2010 to potential GDP arose because of
revisions to labor input.
Figure
1. Decomposition of the revisions (2010 vs. 2008 vintage) to potential
GDP: Spain
And as you can guess from the drawing by Manu
Cartoons, a large part of that decrease came from an
increase in the Commission’s estimate of structural unemployment: the now infamous NAWRU. The European
Commission uses the non-accelerating wage rate of unemployment (NAWRU) as an
estimate for structural unemployment. We can discuss the pros and cons of NAWRU
as a dynamic measure of structural unemployment in normal times, but the
following graph should basically scream at you that this measure has failed at
separating cyclical and structural unemployment during these extraordinary
times.
Figure
2: Actual unemployment and NAWRU: Spain
So although one can argue that a crisis can temporarily – as
workers need time to adjust to the new sectoral and geographical composition of
jobs – or permanently – because of hysteresis effects – decrease potential
labor input, the size of the adjustments applied by the European Commission
appears clearly inadequate.
Second, did it matter and was it more important than the fiscal
multiplier screw-up in driving austerity?
As pointed out by Real Time Brussels, a reconsideration
of the methods that the European Commission uses for estimating potential
output could now cut the estimated structural deficits of the periphery
countries and mean less austerity given the 0.5% rule of the Fiscal Compact. But
I don’t think that, back in 2010, the structural deficit numbers played an
important role for the countries that were under the heavy pressure of bond
markets as they mostly focused on the nominal deficit and debt to GDP ratio metrics
in designing their consolidation packages.
The structural balance screw-up may have mattered, however, for
Germany (and for other core countries to the extent that their fiscal strategy mostly
mimicked that of Germany) as it designed its consolidation plan for the
2011-2016 period based on the structural balance metric. In my VoxEU piece, you can see that the downward
revision to potential GDP applied to core countries was not negligible. For
Germany, the European Commission revised the potential GDP growth rate by about
0.5 percentage points.
I need to find the output gap and the cyclical-adjustment
parameters used both in 2008 and 2010 by the European Commission to quantify by
how much austerity would have decreased had Germany followed the same
consolidation path (similar speed and end-points in terms of structural
deficit) but used the 2008 vintage version of its potential output estimates
rather the revised 2010 estimates. But my guess is that the consolidation
efforts Germany planned for were to a significant extent unnecessary restrictive, even taking as given its
objective of converging to a structural deficit of 0.35% by 2016.
Given the sheer size of core countries for the euro area, this
operational mess-up may have been quite significant in delivering an inappropriate
overall fiscal stance and hindering rebalancing. As a matter of fact, I wonder
if this operational mess-up wasn’t more important than the fiscal multiplier
screw-up in delivering this outcome. Granted, fiscal consolidation would have
been less drastic in the periphery without the fiscal multiplier screw-up. But
the biggest European fiscal policy failure wasn’t so much that of the periphery,
which had pretty much no choice than drastically consolidate in the absence of
a proper lender of last resort. The biggest fiscal policy mistake was the early consolidation
efforts of the core, which started - and were amplified by the structural balance screw-up - in 2010 although “in
the absence of default risk, debt adjustment should be very gradual”.
Jeremie Cohen-Setton (@JCSBruegel) is a PhD candidate in economics
at UC Berkeley and an Affiliate Fellow at Bruegel. He specializes in
Macroeconomic Policies and Macroeconomic History and worked previously as an
economist at HM Treasury and at Goldman Sachs. Jeremie blogs at ecbwatchers.org and is the main
author of the blogs review at bruegel.org.
The real mess up was the imposition of the SGP itself. It was based on a complete misreading of the cause of the Euro crisis, either due to stupidity or deliberately, i.e. that we are all Greece. The rest is secondary, it;s just a corollary.
ReplyDeleteI'm not sure I get your point. The SGP predates the crisis. Maybe you're referring to the Fiscal Compact, but as you can see in my post the medium term fiscal plan of Germany was designed before the Fiscal Compact was implemented.
DeleteHi Jeremie, as someone with first-hand knowledge of what is happening within the EU's output gap working group, I must tell you that unfortunately there is in reality absolutely no backtracking currently going on re the current nawru and potential output methodology... Regards!
ReplyDeleteI had indeed missed this follow-up report by Matthew Dalton http://online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052702304213904579095481787193644.html. This is very concerning.
DeleteSorry for the anonymity, but my position doesn't allow me to speak out freely...
DeleteJeremie this is an important enough consideration that you should make an appended note on your original post
DeleteJeremie, you might want to take a look at this regarding your question on German fiscal consolidation: www.intereconomics.eu/archive/year/2013/1/843/
ReplyDeleteBest regards
EK
Thanks. Well written piece indeed.
Delete